ADEMU Perspectives #2: When HANK Met SAM – new models for macroeconomic policy, by Morten Ravn

Recent economic events cast doubt on the standard macroeconomic models. ADEMU coordinator Morten Ravn and researcher Vincent Sterk look at new economic models built on the idea that inequality and income risk matter for the business cycle and long-run outcomes. While still in their infancy, these models show promise in addressing the concerns about the old New Keynesian models, and in bringing about a shift in the way that macroeconomists think about aggregate fluctuations and stabilisation policy. This article first appeared on voxeu.org in January 2017.

In a thought provoking speech, Federal Reserve chair Janet Yellen recently expressed her discontent with macroeconomic research, and the guidance it provides in addressing today’s key policy challenges.

In the October 2016 address to the Boston Fed, Yellen asked whether “the events of the past few years have revealed limits in economists’ understanding of the economy,” and if “individual differences within broad groups of actors in the economy can influence aggregate economic outcomes.”

What effect in particular, she asked, does such heterogeneity have on aggregate demand? Are there circumstances in which changes in aggregate demand can have an appreciable, persistent effect on aggregate supply? “What determines inflation?” she queried, noting that although inflation fell during the recession, the decline was modest given how high unemployment rose.

Indeed, the standard New Keynesian (NK) paradigm, which forms the basis of policy analysis in almost all central banks and treasuries, does not provide compelling answers to these questions.

First, the standard NK model assumes a representative household which can perfectly insure against individual income risk. This precludes heterogeneity between households from affecting aggregate demand.

Second, the NK model has been designed to think about how policy can stabilize temporary macroeconomic fluctuations around a given long-run “steady-state” equilibrium, rather than how policy might help to move the economy towards a more desirable long-run outcome.

Third, the lack of deflation in the last few years has been rather puzzling from the perspective of the NK model, which typically predicts deflation once the monetary policy rate becomes constrained by the zero lower bound (see, for example, Benhabib, Schmitt-Grohe and Uribe, 2002, or Mertens and Ravn, 2014).

Introducing HANK and SAM

Recently, a new generation of models which addresses these shortcomings has emerged and is starting to deliver novel insights. While retaining nominal rigidities, as in the NK model, the new models replace the representative agent by heterogeneous households who face uninsurable earnings risk, giving rise to inequality in income, wealth and consumption. These models have been dubbed Heterogeneous Agents New Keynesian (HANK) models, by Kaplan, Moll and Violante (2016).

A common and important source of earnings risk faced by households is unemployment. It is difficult for households to insure perfectly against job loss and unemployment spells for that reason often bring about significant income losses and more so in recessions where unemployment duration also is high (such as the aftermath of the financial crisis). The risk of job loss tends to increase at the onset of recessions and the chances of finding a new job for the unemployed are typically considerably lower in recessions than in booms. By implication, the unemployment-related idiosyncratic risk faced by households is countercyclical but may be affected by stabilization policy. To take this into account, the new generation of models introduce Search and Matching (SAM) frictions into the labor market, see e.g. Ravn and Sterk, 2012 and 2016, or Challe et al, 2016.

Unstable aggregate demand

The interactions between HANK and SAM have important implications for aggregate demand. A deterioration of labor market conditions makes households’ job prospects more uncertain and introduces a precautionary savings motive. Therefore, desired savings rise depressing the aggregate demand for goods.  In the NK setting with uninsurable risk, the inflexibility of prices means that firms react to lower goods demand by cutting back on employment which further stimulate savings desires because labor market outcomes become even gloomier. By contrast, in the standard representative agent NK model, since unemployment is expected to recover in the future, high current unemployment motivates lower desired savings rate in order to smooth consumption over time. Lower desired savings, in turn, stimulates aggregate demand and stabilizes the negative consequences of high unemployment.

One way of gauging the new and old models is from the relationship between real interest rates and labor market tightness, the ratio of job vacancies to unemployment. Tightness is low in recessions and in the representative agent NK model, households have an incentive to borrow in bad times for intertemporal reasons. This implies that real interest rates should move in the opposite direction of tightness in the traditional models. In the new models instead, the precautionary motive gives employed households an incentive to save in bad times inducing a positive relationship between tightness and real rates. Figure 1 illustrates the time series of tightness and real interest rates for the US and provides strong support for the new models.

New role for stabilization policy

A celebrated feature of the NK paradigm is the Taylor Principle, which says that monetary policy interventions can eliminate self-fulfilling expectations-driven fluctuations in the vicinity of the “targeted” outcome by varying the short term nominal interest rates by more than one-to-one in response to changes in inflation. Intuitively, the central bank can nip pessimistic expectations about the future economic conditions in the bud by committing to lower the interest rate were such a scenario to realize. In the new generation of models, however, the Taylor Principle is no longer sufficient to preclude such equilibria. Intuitively, the feedback loop described above amplifies any initial change in expectations, requiring a more aggressive interest rate cut to prevent pessimistic expectations from becoming self-fulfilling. Furthermore, due to the adverse interaction between unemployment, precautionary saving and aggregate demand, small aggregate shocks may produce large changes in aggregate output in the new generation of model. Stabilization policy can intervene in this, for example by addressing the increased savings motive by aiming for lower real interest rates.

Demand-driven long-run stagnation

The new models also have important predictions for long-run outcomes. Following Summers (2014), much discussion has highlighted that economies may have entered a secular stagnation type equilibrium in the aftermath of the Great Recession. Initially proposed by Hansen (1938), secular stagnation refers to extended periods of low growth induced by high savings and low investment. Such outcomes can be rationalized in the new generation of NK models, as it may feature a long-run “unemployment trap”, a steady state in which, due to low demand, firms cut investments in job creation to a minimum, creating high unemployment risk, and hence perpetuating low demand. Again, however, such an outcome might be prevented by sufficiently aggressive stabilization policies.

Understanding missing deflation

The new models also help to explain the recent behaviour of inflation and nominal interest rates. The standard explanation for why central bank policy rates became stuck at (near)-zero levels is that households, for one reason or another, increased their desired savings. This drove down aggregate income and inflation, triggering central banks to cut the policy rate, which eventually became stuck at its lower floor. The standard NK model predicts a substantial amount of deflation in such a scenario, as the representative agents’ desire to borrow during a recession increases the real interest rate. When the nominal interest rate is stuck at zero, the inflation rate is simply the negative of the real interest rate. Given that the real interest rate is not only positive, but even higher than its long-run level, episodes of zero interest rates must be deflationary in the standard model. Figure 2 illustrates the path of core CPI inflation in the Euro Area, the UK and the US. The prediction of substantial deflation is obviously not consistent with the data. The new paradigm, by contrast, can rationalize the data, since higher unemployment spurs precautionary saving, pushing down the real interest rate. If this effect is strong enough, the real rate becomes negative, which implies inflation when the nominal interest rate is stuck at zero.

Conclusion

The new models are built on the idea that inequality and income risk matters for the business cyle and long-run outcomes. While still in their infancy, they show promise of addressing the concerns voiced by Janet Yellen and bring about a shift in the way that macroeconomists think about aggregate fluctuations and stabilization policy. This column only scratches the surface of the insights that can be derived from the new models. In recent work, we analyse these insights more formally, using a simple, analytically tractable model, see Ravn and Sterk, 2016. In this work, we also analyse the amplification of aggregate technology shocks, the relation between monetary policy and financial risk premia, and the determination of aggregate unemployment in a liquidity trap.

Morten Ravn is a professor of economics at University College London, co-director at the Centre for Macroeconomics and a research fellow at the CEPR. A macroeconomist, his recent research examines topics including aggregate demand and idiosyncratic risk, expectations and the crises, fiscal policy and anticipation effects, deep habits, aggregation, heterogeneity and the real exchange rate, and participation choices and macro labor fluctuations. 

References

Benhabib, Jess, Stephanie Schmitt-Grohe and Martin Uribe, 2002, “Avoiding Liquidity Traps,” Journal of Political Economy 110 (3), pp.535-563.

Challe, Edouard, Julien Matheron, Xavier Ragot, and Juan F. Rubio Ramirez, 2016, “Precautionary Saving and Aggregate Demand,” forthcoming, Quantitative Economics.

Hansen, Alvin, 1938, “Full Recovery or Stagnation?” New York: W.W. Norton and Company.

Kaplan, Greg, Benjamin Moll, and Giovanni L. Violante, 2016, “Monetary Policy According to HANK,” manuscript, University of Chicago.

Mertens, Karel and Morten O. Ravn, “Fiscal Policy in an Expectations-Driven Liquidity Trap,” Review of Economic Studies 81(4), pp.1637-1667.

Ravn, Morten O. and Vincent Sterk, 2012, “Job Uncertainty and Deep Recessions,” Discussion paper 1501, Centre for Macroeconomics.

Ravn, Morten O. and Vincent Sterk, 2016, “Macroeconomic Fluctuations with HANK and SAM: An Analytical Approach,” CEPR Discussion Paper no. 1633.

Summers, Lawrence, 2014, “Secular Stagnation? The Future Challenge for Economic Policy,” Institute for New Economic Thinking, Toronto, April 12.

Yellen, Janet, 2016, “Macroeconomic Research After the Crisis”, speech At “The Elusive ‘Great’ Recovery: Causes and Implications for Future Business Cycle Dynamics”, Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, October 14.